مقاله مدیریت ترجمه شده با عنوان استدلال مدیران در فرمت ورد و شامل ترجمه متن زیر می باشد:
Secret of Success: As Christensen's Paradox testifies, finding the secret of success takes more than textbook management
Nov 2003
Robert Heller
Medieval
man searched for the philosopher's stone that could turn base metal
into gold. Managers and entrepreneurs often follow a similar, usually
vain hope. But it needn't be vain, judged by the results of companies in
one industry. They achieved $62 billion in sales in 1976-1994, twenty
times the figure for rivals which hadn't found the stone.
If
that isn't convincing enough, sales per firm in the lagging group only
averaged a cumulative $64.5 million: the successes averaged $1.9 billion
- a difference of 29 times. The statistics come from a truly remarkable
management book by Clayton M. Christensen. Its explicit title, The
Innovator's Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail,
does less than justice to its message, which applies to all managements
and all companies all the time - and not only to innovators.
The
philosopher's stone in the statistics cited above, however, is
innovation in 'disruptive technologies'. The successes 'sought growth by
entering small emerging markets'. The back-markers, in contrast,
pursued growth in large markets. Both groups took risks. The winners
took the chance that an emerging market for the disruptive technology
might not appear at all. The losers accepted the competitive risk of
battling against established companies in established markets - and the
first lesson is that this is fundamentally poor strategy.
MANAGEMENT PARADOX
The
book's wholly convincing thesis, however, is that large companies are
locked into this mode. They are forced by customer demands and
competitive pressures to invest heavily to sustain their existing
strengths and, if possible, to enhance that prowess. This gives rise to
Christensen's Paradox. The conventional explanation when great firms
stumble is that they suffer from 'incompetence, bureaucracy, arrogance,
tired executive blood, poor planning, and short-term investment
horizons.' The Paradox, however, states that large companies fail,
absolutely or relatively, in face of disruptive technologies, not
because they are poorly managed, but because their management is
excellent.
So
how did the failures lose leadership to the new disruptive
technologies? It was because they did exactly what any business school
professor would be happy to recommend:
1. Listen to your customers.
2. Invest aggressively in new technologies that will meet those customers' rising demands for performance.
3. Carefully study and meet market trends.
4. Allocate resources to investments promising the best returns.
The
author, an assistant professor at Harvard Business School, gives
example after example from disk drives, computers, retailing,
steel-making, earth-moving equipment, etc. to show how this good
management can't cope with a disruptive technology; one which introduces
a different category of customers. Typically, these are attracted by
lower prices and by different functionality that together help to
generate new types of product. Equally typically, the disruptive
innovators break all the four rules of good management cited above:
1. They don't listen to customers, because they don't have any.
2. They develop lower-performance products instead of higher.
3. They don't rely on market research, because it's useless in these circumstances.
4. They head off into tiny markets, with sales ranging from zero to insignificant.
Yet
they win and win big, like the successes quoted at the start. The
industry concerned is disk drives. The strategy of the 14-inch drive
industry sums up Christensen's thesis. The manufacturers went to very
great lengths, technically and financially, to satisfy the customers,
who all made mainframe computers. The 8-inch drives introduced by
newcomers like Shugart, Priam and Quantum were no use to these
customers.
The
disks found their market with mini-computers - then a minute segment.
As the segment grew, however, and as the 8-inch disks caught up with the
performance of lower-end 14-inch models, so the latter's makers began
to lose out. Yet two-thirds of the 14-inchers never introduced an 8-inch
model. Those that did were around two years late, and ultimately every
14-inch drive maker was driven from the industry.
To
repeat, this wasn't because of any real management incompetence, but
because of its opposite. The 8-inch drives offered smaller margins and a
far smaller market, and the customers didn't want them. The book firmly
establishes the concept of 'value networks', in which customers and
supplier develop a shared interest in a given technology which suits
both their purposes - including their profit objectives. The folly of
ignoring the new emerging market is only clear in hindsight.
UP-MARKET PROFITS
At
the time, dismissal of the down-market potential was true wisdom: that
way, neither profit nor revenues lay in wait. Going up-market, however,
offered both. Here again is the standard business school and industry
lesson. Every manager is urged to head for the top left-hand corner of
the price/performance matrix, where you win the highest price for the
highest quality. That optimises the present - but may undermine, and
even eliminate, the future.
To
express the position another way, firms and individuals naturally play
to their strengths - what they are good at, which has worked well in the
past and still works well. The time comes, however, when these
strengths are threatened by obsolescence - even though they are still
paying off.
That
was IBM's recurrent nightmare. The company may have deserved its
sky-high management reputation, at least in part, but it derived its
vast profits and massive market strength from serving large corporate
customers. Although it eventually reacted very effectively to the rise
of both the minicomputer and the PC, its natural bent was towards those
same customers. But the phenomenal growth in PC sales lay outside the
large corporates - and IBM's market share, once 80%, slumped to single
figures.
Again,
this isn't a failing peculiar to IBM. In disk drives, Seagate, the
5.25-inch leader, came late into 3.5-inch disks - and by 1991 hadn't
sold a single product to what turned out to be their prime users,
manufacturers of portable, laptop and notebook computers. So there is
everybody's problem. The biggest opportunity and the greatest threat may
well lie outside your existing business and value network. You can't,
however, just abandon the latter, because that network provides your
current highly satisfactory profits.
The
whole organisation, and the management mind-set, are geared, quite
rightly, to what is. How can the same organisation react effectively to
what isn't - and may never be? Christensen's unequivocal answer is that
it can't. The existing organisation will never suceed with a disruptive
technology. The book cites Woolworth in the US, which attempted to
combat the discount stores by opening its own Woolco outlets and
simultaneously expanding the traditional variety stores.
The
effort failed even more abysmally than IBM's move to absorb its
phenomenally succesful PC operation into the mainstream organisation.
The Woolcos disappeared completely. IBM, as noted, lost massive amounts
of market share. Yet originally the PC operation was a model response to
the innovator's dilemma. It's a solution that I've advocated for many
years, and to which Christensen's meticulous studies give added force.
KEY PRESCRIPTIONS
The
PC activity was sited well away from any other IBM centre, in Boca
Raton, Florida, under independent management with a distinct mandate. It
met excellently most of the book's key prescriptions:
1. Match the size of the organisation to the size of the market.
2. Learn about the market and its customers as you go along.
3. Get in early, while the market has still to be proved.
4. Accept the inevitability of mistakes.
5. Recognise the weaknesses of disruptive technologies and their strengths.
This
sounds like an argument for the 'skunk works', an R&D organisation
given a specific task and located in a site which makes interference
unlikely. Many a skunk-works failed, however, usually because either the
sponsoring management didn't have real faith in the project, or the
R&D wasn't linked to manufacture and marketing. The catastrophic
failure of Xerox to exploit any of the brilliant, epoch-making PC
discoveries at its Palo Alto Research Center sprang from separation of
the scientists from manufacturing and marketing.
There's
an apparent contradiction between what happened to PARC and the
argument for siting new activities well away from existing ones. But it
is only apparent: the spun-off activity should be a fully integrated
operation, not (like PARC) a self-contained outfit with no commercial
affiliations. Without a sponsor, even brilliant research and development
will be lost. Even with a sponsor, though, the independent operation
may not produce the right disruptive technology or market it
appropriately to the different categories of customers who become
involved.
The
innovators have to learn how to play from weakness. Since they can't
compete with the established business for the established customers, and
initally have little or no idea of where their products will sell, they
have to create new strength. They have to learn how to find new
customers and open up new markets - from which brilliant success can
spring. That, however, doesn't makes it any easier to encompass
disruptive change when those markets, in turn, become established.
What
happened to the 14-inch disk drive makers was repeated again and again
every time a generation of new boy entrepreneurs reduced disk sizes. The
rich old boys proved incapable of resisting the competition, even
though it used the identical approach that had made their own wealth
(and killed their competition). The main antidote is to accept that in
every business disruptive technologies or the equivalent lie in wait -
developments which will one day enlarge and upset the market to your
disadvantage.
One
of Britain's classic entrepreneurial success stories, that of J. C.
Bamford, came from disruption. In 1947 Joe Bamford produced the very
first hydraulic excavator - a little machine, designed to go on the back
of tractors, that was entirely unsuitable for the major construction
jobs. These were dominated by cable-actuated systems.
DIDN'T NEED, COULDN'T USE
Their
makers studied the hydraulic newcomers, but, to quote Christensen,
'Hydraulics was a technology that their customers didn't need - indeed
couldn't use.' When hydraulic machines could finally match cable, it was
too late for the cable champions to react. JCB and the other hydraulic
manufacturers took most of the market. In the process, Joe and his son
Sir Anthony took sales to great heights: £700 million in 1995. Their
combined fortunes, created by a company that remained resolutely
private, hit £800 million in 1996.
At
the start, the main strength of challengers like the Bamfords lies in
their highly adaptive approach. In these disruptive businesses, with
their uncertain markets, there is no alternative to the points made
earlier: to learn as you go along, and to make false starts and
mistakes, but react swiftly until you find the better path. For
perfectly sound reasons, big companies discipline this behaviour out of
existence in their mainstream operations. That's why, as IBM showed, by
far the best way for them to avoid the 14-inch fate is to establish and
finance some imitation start-ups themselves - independent outfits that
can attack small emerging markets in the style of small emerging
companies.
That
style involves eight principles that separate the winners from the
also-rans, and the corpocrats from the entrepreneurs. The Opportunity
Octet is highly valuable in any business, but in start-ups it is
decisive. Winners in the start-up stakes....
1. Reward risk-taking and don't punish failure
2. Give new ideas top, top priority
3. Allow those ideas to develop freely
4. Put great performance above good order
5. Compete fiercely with themselves
6. Enlist professional managers in good time
7. Share financial rewards widely and richly
8. Go for market share first and foremost
Much
of the Octet (derived from a Business Week study of Silicon Valley) has
been strongly advised for all managers in Thinking Managers. Out of
sheer necessity, the IT whiz-kids have been forced to abandon
traditional, hierarchical ways and have learnt to live with chaos in the
interests of 'super-speed and can-do culture.' That pair form the pure
milk of entrepreneurism, which produces an unprecedented flow of cream
in the hands of unconventional managements.
Thus,
to gain its potent market position on the Internet (8) start-up
Netscape famously just gave away its browsers. You simply have to forget
old inhibitions. For instance, competing with yourself (2) means not
being afraid to cannibalise your existing products: if you don't eat
your children, someone else will. Seagate's Al Shugart, the ace
entrepreneur of the disk drive, is only half-joking: 'Sometimes I think
we'll see the day when you introduce a product in the morning and
announce its end of life at the end of the day.'
FOUR DIFFERENCES
The
Opportunity Octet are tactical necessities. But they should rest on
four strategic principles which mark out winning strategies from the
runners-up and flops. Winners concentrate on the winning hand; cover
every bet; work with strong partners; and think really big. A wondrous
example of big thinking is Finland's Nokia, whose cellular phone
technology has taken it to a market value of $9 billion. Once the Finns
had spotted their winning opportunity in the cellular potential, they
poured in resources to achieve a quarter of world phone sales.
That
meant intense concentration. For the sake of cellular, Nokia abandoned
paper, tyres, metals, other electronics, cables, TV sets and its PC
interests - sold to ICL. That tight focus, however, is only part of the
story. It won't save you from Christensen's Paradox. That's where
covering every bet comes in. The failed market leaders trapped by the
Paradox actually saw that necessity - they not only developed the
disruptive technologies themselves, but often took the development to
the point of a business proposal. But it never made economic sense to
take the technology to market - not within the established organisation.
So don't try.
Independent
start-ups are not the only answer. You can also take partners. The
Silicon Valley giants have formed the good habit of investing in small
start-ups that have promising ideas. Cisco Systems has bought or
invested in 34 of them in three years: Intel has set aside $500 million
for similar purposes. If the investment succeeds with a new technology,
the investor is in on the ground floor; if the start-up succeeds
financially, the investor cashes in; and the odds are, of course, that
technological and financial breakthroughs will go hand-in-hand.
If
the 14-inch drive makers had invested in the 8-inch disrupters, the
leaders wouldn't have lost out - provided, of course, that they had
allowed the challengers to follow their own logic. Hewlett-Packard did
precisely that when setting free a new organisation to make ink-jet
printers that would challenge its own immensely profitable position in
laser printers. The disruptive technology then worked to H-P's overall
advantage and followed the logic of Christensen's Paradox. Anything else
invites eventual disruption by others - followed, if you're 14-inched,
by destruction.
:: برچسبها:
مقاله ,
مدیریت ,
ترجمه ,
شده ,
با ,
عنوان ,
استدلال ,
:: بازدید از این مطلب : 127
|
امتیاز مطلب : 0
|
تعداد امتیازدهندگان : 0
|
مجموع امتیاز : 0